Deer milk is not the future: How property impacts agroecological food production

by Olivia Oldham
PhD Candidate | Global Academy of Agriculture and Food Systems, University of Edinburgh

If you're reading this newsletter, I probably don't need to explain to you that the food system is not working—either for people or planet—and that agroecology and food sovereignty are alternatives worth striving for. While there are lots of things we could be doing to work towards those goals, one of the key elements we should be thinking about is land. And, because the rules of property structure, things like who gets access to land, how they are able to access it, and what they are able to do with it once they've got it, then we also need to be thinking about property.

What is property?

But what is property? You might think it means ownership, or 'the stuff I own'. And that would be fair enough—that's what most people mean when they talk about property. But for a lawyer, property means something a bit different. It means a relationship between people about a thing, not the thing itself. 

Sometimes, lawyers talk about that relationship being made up of a "bundle of rights". Think of it like a bundle of sticks. Each of those sticks represents a right. Keeping with property in land, those rights might include the right to keep others out; or the right to make decisions about what happens on the land; or even the right to alienate—that is, to sell or otherwise get rid of it. We might, if we were being particularly radical, even think about some of those sticks representing a responsibility, too. Maybe, the responsibility not to degrade ecosystems, or the responsibility to use the land for the common good (like in Brazil, where this responsibility is actually set out in the constitution).

So the idea of private ownership is actually a very particular bundle of rights that has become so common that we tend to just equate it with property, full stop. But, in fact, there are lots of different ways of putting that bundle together—and we'll get to that a bit later.

Private ownership: how good?

First, let's deal with private ownership, which is at the heart of our system of property and farming here in Aotearoa New Zealand. People like private ownership for a lot of reasons. The rights I mentioned earlier—keeping others out, making decisions, and alienation—mean that farmers who own their land can feel secure. No landlord can kick them off or tell them how to farm, and making long-term investments in farm infrastructure or ecosystems feels less risky. That right to sell, in particular, can be appealing because it allows the land to be used as leverage for a mortgage, or as an asset the farmer can cash out to fund their retirement or support their kids to buy their first farm, or whatever else they may want to do.

The problem is, these benefits of private ownership—while they can be great for individual farmers, and can be appealing for agroecological producers, too—can have negative impacts for the food system as a whole. They can actually end up undermining efforts to shift the food system towards agroecology and food sovereignty. Not to mention that, in Aotearoa New Zealand, the entire system of private ownership is built upon the dispossession of tangata whenua.

For starters, that autonomy that can be so good for the individual farmer, also means that landowners are free to farm in ways that degrade te taiao and that don't produce healthy, nutritious food for local, regional and national communities but instead pursue whatever goals the farmer wants—usually, profit.

"Ah," I hear you say, "but if it's a good farmer, who is growing agroecologically and wants to promote food sovereignty, then they don't care about profit! They are motivated by other things, like stewardship of ecosystems, respect for Papatūanuku, and care for the people they feed!"

And in some ways, you'd be right. Most agroecological farmers are driven by those things. My best friend is one of them, as are many others who I know and deeply respect. If I ever get myself out from behind a computer and into a field, I will be too. But the problem is, private property ownership creates a system where this is no longer about choices. 

At some point, if the farmer wants to keep farming, they are almost inevitably going to have to prioritise profit over some of their other goals, unless they (a) are very lucky; or (b) inherited their land or the money to buy it (which you could say is the same thing). Because that famous 'security' being a landowner gives you is only secure as long as you keep up with your mortgage repayments—that is, the cost of land. 

Alienability, the right to get rid, is so central to private ownership that some people have argued that, without this right, it isn't private ownership at all! But when you're behind on your mortgage repayments, that 'right' starts to look very much like a curse. 

Here's where it gets kind of complicated. 

We all know what happens when mortgage repayments aren't met—eventually, the bank will repossess the property, and sell it to someone else to get their investment back. Usually, the person who is able to afford that land is the person with the most money. This can lead to land concentration, where more and more land is owned by fewer and fewer people—but we're not going to focus on that today. Instead, we're going to focus on what determines the price of the land at the time that it's sold. First and foremost, land values are determined by how much money people think they can make off the land in the future—as rent, profit, or both. Those amounts are determined by what has been produced on the land in the past, as well as what the land might be able to be used for in the future—whether that's for a dairy conversion, planting pine forest, or subdividing it for a housing development. 

This has major consequences for agroecological farmers. Not only because, very often, it pushes them onto marginal land which might be less productive, less climactically favourable, or very far away from markets, or even prices them out of the market entirely; but perhaps even more importantly because it means that when those agroecological farmers do manage to buy the land, their mortgage repayments reflect what they could be making if they didn't prioritise their agroecological principles and instead farmed to maximise their yield—and their profit. They can do this by lowering their ecological and social standards (and the first thing they do, typically, is to 'self-exploit'—meaning that they work themselves to the bone and barely pay themselves (if at all)—to make the numbers add up. Because they so want to make it work). Or, they can do this by seeking out higher value markets, like organics—which partly explains why organic food often costs so much, and why lots of organic farmers in Aotearoa New Zealand are focused on exports, rather than domestic markets. Sometimes, they might turn to novel products—like kiwifruit once was, or the recent moves by Pāmu to develop deer milk, into a marketable product.

Farmers in most cases are, to use a fancy term, 'market dependent'—meaning they are forced, economically speaking, to sell what they produce on the market, in order to earn enough money to pay for the land. So, in the end, it often doesn't matter very much whether farmers want to farm agroecologically—the cost of land, which is a direct consequence of private ownership's central right of alienability (within a capitalist system), can force them to undermine those goals. 

We also shouldn't forget that these dynamics of private ownership are not just harmful to farmers and the food system—they are also central to the continued dispossession of tangata whenua, and the ongoing exclusion of Māori from access to and authority over their ancestral lands and territories. 

That seems bad…what do we do?

The good thing about seeing property as a bundle of rights (and responsibilities) is that we can repackage that bundle in different ways. One good idea that has been floating around for a very long time is the commons. Basically, the commons is a way of governing a resource (so, a property relation) that is neither public nor private, but collectively managed by a self-governing, well-defined community. And they have the potential to overcome some of those problems with private ownership.

You may have heard of the 'tragedy of the commons', or the idea that the commons can't work because humans are tragically but unavoidably selfish. This is a simple theory but unfortunately, it's simply incorrect. It has been repeatedly demonstrated—both by mainstream economists as well as by many traditional and Indigenous societies—that it is entirely possible for communities to effectively govern resources, given appropriate institutional design.

There are, around the world, a number of organisations building on the principles and ideas of the commons to develop new ways of understanding and putting into practice property rights and responsibilities that might be more enabling of agroecological, food sovereign food systems. For example, in the UK (where I work) there is the Ecological Land Cooperative, which holds land collectively and grants secure, lifetime leases to new entrant farmers at affordable rates, so long as they adhere to agroecological management provisions. The Agrarian Trust in the USA, and Kulturland in Germany do similar things. Another approach is the idea of public-commons partnerships, where the local council and a commons association made up of community members and different stakeholders co-own and co-govern local land. At a bigger scale, the Scottish Parliament has passed a number of land reform laws which give communities a right of first refusal on local land, and even has (some) money available to help them buy it. 

Here in Aotearoa, Village Agrarians is working to put issues around land access and, crucially, land ownership, on the agenda. Their land matching service works to reduce barriers to land access within the existing framework of property rights. More broadly they are working to develop greater awareness of the ways in which private ownership of land undermines agroecology, ultimately aiming to be part of developing alternative forms of ownership and stewardship.

Of course, any commoning initiatives here in Aotearoa New Zealand would have to be built upon an understanding that much of the land which could be 'commoned' was stolen from tangata whenua. This means that any work to begin 'commoning' land would need to centre movements and demands for land return, and ongoing conversations on constitutional transformation, such as the discussions and action stemming from the Matike Mai report. Land commoning would look different in Aotearoa New Zealand than in other parts of the world—and this is something to be embraced and addressed head on, with tangata whenua leading in any endeavour. This may look like a public-commons-iwi partnership, for instance. Or it may look like existing iwi owners holding farmland in trust for ecological stewardship by whānau or others. It may look like land reform that creates an iwi right to buy as well as, or instead of, a community right to buy. Or it may look like none of these—commoning may not even be the right framing. The key here is to centre Māori leadership, and for Pākehā and other tauiwi to be willing to ensure that any agenda for shifting property relations reflects Māori needs and desires.

I guess what I'm trying to say is that I don't think deer milk is the future. But the commons, as one possible foundation for a decolonial vision for a food sovereign, agroecological Aotearoa New Zealand, just might be. 



New National Policy Statement for Protecting Highly Productive Land

By Leigh McKenzie

Central government recently brought in a new National Policy Statement under the Resource Management Act 1991 to protect Highly Productive Land. The purpose of this new policy is to protect high class soils for food and fibre production for the future as it is a non-renewable resource. The new policy is to direct new housing developments and subdivisions away from Highly Productive Land.

The subdivision of land for urban development and lifestyle blocks has been encroaching on and diminishing the usefulness of Highly Productive Land in New Zealand. Highly Productive Land in the new policy, refers to land with high class soils and suitable land-use zoning for primary production. The policy uses local council’s existing land-use zones, but the policy is to prevent future subdivision and housing developments in these precious areas of productive land. 

As an organisation promoting food production in tandem with protection of soils, this new National Policy Statement is intriguing. Will the new policy help our cause for sustainable food production? How might it affect small-scale market gardeners who we want to support? Does it allow for access to equitable housing, including options such as tiny homes? How does it fit with increasing pine plantations? This article strives to answer these questions.  

The Issue


Figure 1: Map of Highly Productive Land protected by the new National Policy Statement 2022. Source: Landcare Research (2022) ‘Baseline Highly Productive Land’, URL: https://ourenvironment.scinfo.org.nz/maps-and-tools/app/Land%20Capability/lri_luc_hpl, accessed 28/11/2022.

About 15% of land in Aotearoa New Zealand (3,830,000 hectares) is estimated to be highly productive. In the last 20 years, over 35,000 hectares of Highly Productive Land has been lost to urban or rural residential development, and the new Urban Development Policy (2020) encourages more. Furthermore, lifestyle blocks under 8 hectares occupy more than 170,000 hectares of Highly Productive Land. This National Policy Statement for Highly Productive Land requires the country’s most productive land to be identified and managed to prevent inappropriate subdivision, use, and development. The policy came about following the Our Land (2018) report which analysed the pressures facing New Zealand’s most productive soils.

How It Works - Implementation

The policy is now part of the Resource Management Act 1991, which means that all local authorities have to take it into account when approving resource consent applications and writing their plans for how land in the district will be managed. For example, if you are wanting to subdivide an area identified as Highly Productive Land for housing, then you would have to apply to your local council for permission to do that through a resource consent. The local authority would see that your proposal would interfere with Highly Productive Land being used for primary production (production from agricultural, pastoral, horticultural, or forestry activities) and be unlikely to be approved. To gain approval, you would need to prove that your proposal is temporary or will not compromise the viability of using it for primary production. 

Local and Regional Authorities will have three years from 2022 to identify and map Highly Productive Land. They then have a further two years to update their district and regional plans to implement the policy.

Highly Productive Land protected by this policy

Highly Productive Land accounts for high class soils, and existing Land Use Classes which are how Councils have zoned their land, therefore identifying land that is available and suitable for primary production. 

In Otago, where I am writing, the new policy is expected to protect 3,080 hectares of Highly Productive Land with Land Use Class 1 (most versatile multiple-use land, minimal limitations, highly suitable for cropping, viticulture, berry fruit, pastoralism, tree crops, and forestry), 47,320 hectares of Highly Productive Land with Land Use Class 2 (very good multiple-use land, slight limitations, suitable for cropping, viticulture, berry fruit, pastoralism, tree crops, and forestry), and 343,300 hectares of Highly Productive Land with Land Use Class 3 (moderate limitations, restricting crop types and intensity of cultivation, suitable for cropping, viticulture, berry fruit, pastoralism, tree crops, and forestry). 

Impact on small-scale market gardeners

The policy directs that Highly Productive Land should be used for land-based primary production. Also for activities that address public health and safety, encourage indigenous biodiversity, or are small-scale or temporary and have no impact on the productive capacity of the land. This is great for small-scale market gardeners as it means less land that is good quality for growing on will be snatched up for housing subdivisions. However, if a small-scale grower wants to buy a smaller parcel of land, the land is less likely to be subdivisible. As long as the grower can prove the viability of the small parcel of land for primary production, then the subdivision would be allowed by this policy. 

One complication to consider is the implication for land access. This policy prioritises large sections of land which could make it less accessible, as it would come at a higher upfront cost due to the scale. This leads to the same questions in equitable land access for small-scale growers that our organisation wants to address. 

Implications for housing 

If you wish to subdivide your Highly Productive Land, or rezone it for urban development or rural lifestyle, you will need resource consent or undertake a plan change. In the case of subdivision, you will need to demonstrate that the productive capacity of the land will be retained, or that existing permanent or long-term restrictions on the land mean it is no longer viable for land-based primary production and therefore not fit for primary production. 

Since tiny houses are temporary/not permanent, it seems they may be allowed on Highly Productive Land under this policy. The policy also allows for supporting infrastructure for primary production such as sorting sheds. Good news for our small-scale growers!

However, there is an exemption in the policy where local councils are allowed to rezone Highly Productive Land for urban development if there is no other option possible for the objectives of the Urban Development Policy (2020) to be achieved, and if the benefits of using it for housing outweighs the long-term costs of losing the Highly Productive Land. 

This seems like a risky exemption to have in the policy, as the Urban Development policy is written to allow free building development on land, outwards and upwards. If a council can find that rezoning is the way to go, it might be easy for them to justify and therefore compromise the integrity and strength of this policy for protecting our precious soils. 

What about primary production practices that degrade soils?

There is increasing concern in New Zealand that productive land is being taken up for pine plantations. Village Agrarians supports all work to address climate change, but pine plantations are not an approach we endorse. The lack of biodiversity that these plantations are able to host is at odds with creating a sustainable future, not to mention the devastating impacts of clear-felling if the forests are eventually harvested. The downfalls of pine plantations makes this question worth investigating. 

This policy protects Highly Productive Land for land-based primary production. In the policy, land based primary production means production from agricultural, pastoral, horticultural, or

forestry activities that are reliant on the soil resource of the land. In other words, it does not really restrict the kind of primary production that Highly Productive Land can be used for, so it seems pine forestry will be allowed to resume on Highly Productive Land.

Although the policy does not restrict the use of Highly Productive Land for pine plantations or other primary production practices that deplete soils, it does have clauses that encourage indigenous biodiversity, and for councils to consider cumulative adverse effects of activities on Highly Productive Land. This may mean that other activities such as horticulture and indigenous biodiversity would be prioritised over more intensive primary production like pine plantations and conventional farms, but these practices that can deplete soils are not inhibited by the policy.

Conclusion

To conclude, this policy gives legal gravity to protecting our most productive land. It is great to see the government giving importance to and taking action to protect our precious soil resources for primary production. Giving this non-renewable resource legal recognition is a great step forward for sustainable land management. 

This new national policy means that highly productive land is protected for the future. However the policy could have consequences for equitable land access for small-scale growers by prioritising large sections of land, making it more expensive to access. This leads to the same challenges Village Agrarians has identified for achieving more equitable land access. 

The policy also has an exemption which allows Councils to rezone land for urban development if there is no alternative for providing sufficient housing. Housing has been pushed via the Urban Development Policy 2020 in order to address the housing crisis, which is critical, but we can’t afford housing at the cost of our non-renewable resources for food security. 

Pine plantations are still allowed on Highly Productive Land by the policy, but it does require councils to encourage indigenous biodiversity and consider cumulative effects of the activity that Highly Productive Land is used for. This may mean that other activities would be prioritised over pine plantations, but they are not inhibited by the policy. 

The policy doesn’t prevent Highly Productive Land from being used for practices such as monocultures or intensive grazing which would deplete the value of the soils it is intended to protect. We would like to see the policy go a step further and actually protect the soil by disallowing these activities on it, since they have already identified that it is valuable. 

Overall, this policy seems to be a positive outcome for protecting our soil resources. However, it comes with the caveat of potential issues for equitable land access, and urban development. If urban development can still be justified, it can go ahead. It also seems too permissive around the kinds of practices allowed on these valuable soils. The policy seems promising, but only time will tell whether it works to create meaningful positive change!